Մասնակից:Anyut2020/Ավազարկղ6
Ակադեմիական կարիերա
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]1977 թվականի սեպտեմբերին Քրուգմանը դարձել է Եյլի համալսարանի պրոֆեսորի օգնական։ 1979թ. ընդունվել Է Մասաչուսեթսի տեխնոլոգիական ինստիտուտի ֆակուլտետ։ 1982-1983թթ. Քրուգմանն աշխատել է Ռեյգանի Սպիտակ տանը՝ որպես տնտեսական խորհրդատուների խորհրդի անդամ։ 1984 թվականին նա վերադարձել է Մասաչուսեթսի տեխնոլոգիական ինստիտուտ՝ արդեն որպես պրոֆեսոր։ Կրուգմանը դասավանդել է նաև Սթենֆորդի համալսարանում, Եյլի համալսարանում և Լոնդոնի տնտեսագիտության և քաղաքական գիտությունների դպրոցում[1]:
2000 թվականին Քրուգմանը ընդունվել է Փրինսթոնի համալսարան որպես տնտեսագիտության և միջազգային հարաբերությունների պրոֆեսոր։ Ներկայումս նա աշխատում է նաև Լոնդոնի տնտեսագիտության և քաղաքական գիտությունների դպրոցում և երեսուն միջազգային տնտեսական կազմակերպությունների խմբի (G30) անդամ է: 1979 թվականից Նա Տնտեսական հետազոտությունների ազգային բյուրոյի գիտաշխատող է։ 2010 թվականին Քրուգմանն եղել է Արևելյան տնտեսական ասոցիացիայի նախագահը։ 2014 թվականի փետրվարին նա հայտարարել է, որ դուրս է գալու Փրինսթոնի համալսարանից և 2015 թվականի հունիսին միանալու է Նյու Յորքի քաղաքային համալսարանի դասախոսական կազմին[2]:
Փոլ Քրուգմանը մեծ քանակությամբ աշխատանքներ է գրել միջազգային տնտեսագիտության մասին, այդ թվում՝ միջազգային առևտրի, տնտեսական աշխարհագրության և միջազգային ֆինանսների վերաբերյալ: «Research Papers in Economics» (RePEc) նախագիծը այն դասում է աշխարհի ամենաազդեցիկ տնտեսագետների շարքին[3]։ Քրուգմանի՝ «Միջազգային տնտեսագիտություն: Տեսություն և քաղաքականություն», որը գրված է նաև Մորիս Օբստֆելդի համահեղինակությամբ, միջազգային տնտեսագիտության բակալավրի ավարտական կուրսի ստանդարտ դասագիրք է: Քրուգմանը նաև ավարտական կուրսի ուսանողների համար նախատեսված նյութի համահեղինակ է Ռոբին Ուելսի հետ միասին, վերջինս նշել է, որ շատ ոգևորված է Պոլ Սամուելսոնի դասական գրքի առաջին հրատարակությունից[4]: Քրուգմանը գրել է տնտեսագիտական, երբեմն էլ միջազգային տնտեսագիտության, եկամտի բաշխման և պետության քաղաքականության թեմաներով աշխատանքներ հանրության լայն շրջանակների համար:
Նոբելյան հանձնաժողովը հայտարարել է, որ Քրուգմանի հիմնական ներդրումը իր մասշտաբից տնտեսման ազդեցության վերլուծությունն է, որը զուգորդվում է այն ենթադրության հետ, որ սպառողները գնահատում են բազմազանությունը, միջազգային առևտուրը և տնտեսական գործունեությունը[5]:
Փոլ Քրուգմանը կարդում է դասախոսություն Ֆրանկֆուրտում՝ Գերմանիայի ազգային գրադարանում
New trade theory
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]Prior to Krugman's work, trade theory (see David Ricardo and Heckscher–Ohlin model) emphasized trade based on the comparative advantage of countries with very different characteristics, such as a country with a high agricultural productivity trading agricultural products for industrial products from a country with a high industrial productivity. However, in the 20th century, an ever-larger share of trade occurred between countries with similar characteristics, which is difficult to explain by comparative advantage. Krugman's explanation of trade between similar countries was proposed in a 1979 paper in the Journal of International Economics, and involves two key assumptions: that consumers prefer a diverse choice of brands, and that production favors economies of scale.[6] Consumers' preference for diversity explains the survival of different versions of cars like Volvo and BMW. However, because of economies of scale, it is not profitable to spread the production of Volvos all over the world; instead, it is concentrated in a few factories and therefore in a few countries (or maybe just one). This logic explains how each country may specialize in producing a few brands of any given type of product, instead of specializing in different types of products.
Krugman modeled a 'preference for diversity' by assuming a CES utility function like that in a 1977 paper by Avinash Dixit and Joseph Stiglitz.[7][8] Many models of international trade now follow Krugman's lead, incorporating economies of scale in production and a preference for diversity in consumption.[5][9] This way of modeling trade has come to be called New Trade Theory.[10]
Krugman's theory also took into account transportation costs, a key feature in producing the "home market effect", which would later feature in his work on the new economic geography. The home market effect "states that, ceteris paribus, the country with the larger demand for a good shall, at equilibrium, produce a more than proportionate share of that good and be a net exporter of it."[10] The home market effect was an unexpected result, and Krugman initially questioned it, but ultimately concluded that the mathematics of the model were correct.[10]
When there are economies of scale in production, it is possible that countries may become 'locked into' disadvantageous patterns of trade.[11] Krugman points out that although globalization has been positive on a whole, since the 1980s the process known as hyper-globalization has at least played a part in rising inequality.[12] Nonetheless, trade remains beneficial in general, even between similar countries, because it permits firms to save on costs by producing at a larger, more efficient scale, and because it increases the range of brands available and sharpens the competition between firms.[13] Krugman has usually been supportive of free trade and globalization.[14][15] He has also been critical of industrial policy, which New Trade Theory suggests might offer nations rent-seeking advantages if "strategic industries" can be identified, saying it's not clear that such identification can be done accurately enough to matter.[16]
New economic geography
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]It took an interval of eleven years, but ultimately Krugman's work on New Trade Theory (NTT) converged to what is usually called the "new economic geography" (NEG), which Krugman began to develop in a seminal 1991 paper, "Increasing Returns and Economic Geography", published in the Journal of Political Economy.[17] In Krugman's own words, the passage from NTT to NEG was "obvious in retrospect; but it certainly took me a while to see it. ... The only good news was that nobody else picked up that $100 bill lying on the sidewalk in the interim."[18] This would become Krugman's most-cited academic paper: by early 2009, it had 857 citations, more than double his second-ranked paper.[10] Krugman called the paper "the love of my life in academic work."[19]
The "home market effect" that Krugman discovered in NTT also features in NEG, which interprets agglomeration "as the outcome of the interaction of increasing returns, trade costs and factor price differences."[10] If trade is largely shaped by economies of scale, as Krugman's trade theory argues, then those economic regions with most production will be more profitable and will therefore attract even more production. That is, NTT implies that instead of spreading out evenly around the world, production will tend to concentrate in a few countries, regions, or cities, which will become densely populated but will also have higher levels of income.[5][20]
Agglomeration and economies of scale
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]Manufacturing is characterized by increasing returns to scale and less restrictive and expansive land qualifications as compared to agricultural uses. So, geographically where can manufacturing be predicted to develop? Krugman states that manufacturing's geographical range is inherently limited by economies of scale, but also that manufacturing will establish and accrue itself in an area of high demand. Production that occurs adjacent to demand will result in lower transportation costs, but demand, as a result, will be greater due to concentrated nearby production. These forces act upon one another simultaneously, producing manufacturing and population agglomeration. Population will increase in these areas due to the more highly developed infrastructure and nearby production, therefore lowering the expense of good, while economies of scale provide varied choices of goods and services. These forces will feed into each other until the greater portion of the urban population and manufacturing hubs are concentrated into a relatively insular geographic area.[21]
International finance
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]Krugman has also been influential in the field of international finance. As a graduate student, Krugman visited the Federal Reserve Board where Stephen Salant and Dale Henderson were completing their discussion paper on speculative attacks in the gold market. Krugman adapted their model for the foreign exchange market, resulting in a 1979 paper on currency crises in the Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, which showed that misaligned fixed exchange rate regimes are unlikely to end smoothly but instead end in a sudden speculative attack.[22] Krugman's paper is considered one of the main contributions to the 'first generation' of currency crisis models,[23][24] and it is his second-most-cited paper (457 citations as of early 2009).[10]
In response to the global financial crisis of 2008, Krugman proposed, in an informal "mimeo" style of publication,[25] an "international finance multiplier", to help explain the unexpected speed with which the global crisis had occurred. He argued that when, "highly leveraged financial institutions [HLIs], which do a lot of cross-border investment [. ... ] lose heavily in one market ... they find themselves undercapitalized, and have to sell off assets across the board. This drives down prices, putting pressure on the balance sheets of other HLIs, and so on." Such a rapid contagion had hitherto been considered unlikely because of "decoupling" in a globalized economy.[26][27][28] He first announced that he was working on such a model on his blog, on October 5, 2008.[29] Within days of its appearance, it was being discussed on some popular economics-oriented blogs.[30][31] The note was soon being cited in papers (draft and published) by other economists,[32] even though it had not itself been through ordinary peer review processes.
Macroeconomics and fiscal policy
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]Կաղապար:Macroeconomics sidebar Krugman has done much to revive discussion of the liquidity trap as a topic in economics.[33][34][35][36] He recommended pursuing aggressive fiscal policy and unconventional monetary policy to counter Japan's lost decade in the 1990s, arguing that the country was mired in a Keynesian liquidity trap.[37][38][39] The debate he started at that time over liquidity traps and what policies best address them continues in the economics literature.[40]
Krugman had argued in The Return of Depression Economics that Japan was in a liquidity trap in the late 1990s, since the central bank could not drop interest rates any lower to escape economic stagnation.[41] The core of Krugman's policy proposal for addressing Japan's liquidity trap was inflation targeting, which, he argued "most nearly approaches the usual goal of modern stabilization policy, which is to provide adequate demand in a clean, unobtrusive way that does not distort the allocation of resources."[39] The proposal appeared first in a web posting on his academic site.[42] This mimeo-draft was soon cited, but was also misread by some as repeating his earlier advice that Japan's best hope was in "turning on the printing presses", as recommended by Milton Friedman, John Makin, and others.[43][44][45]
Krugman has since drawn parallels between Japan's 'lost decade' and the late 2000s recession, arguing that expansionary fiscal policy is necessary as the major industrialized economies are mired in a liquidity trap.[46] In response to economists who point out that the Japanese economy recovered despite not pursuing his policy prescriptions, Krugman maintains that it was an export-led boom that pulled Japan out of its economic slump in the late-90s, rather than reforms of the financial system.[47]
Krugman was one of the most prominent advocates of the 2008–2009 Keynesian resurgence, so much so that economics commentator Noah Smith referred to it as the "Krugman insurgency."[48][49][50] His view that most peer-reviewed macroeconomic research since the mid-1960s is wrong, preferring simpler models developed in the 1930s, has been criticized by some modern economists, like John H. Cochrane.[51] In June 2012, Krugman and Richard Layard launched A manifesto for economic sense, where they call for greater use of fiscal stimulus policy to reduce unemployment and foster growth.[52] The manifesto received over four thousand signatures within two days of its launch,[53] and has attracted both positive and critical responses.[54][55]
Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]Krugman was awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (informally the Nobel Prize in Economics), the sole recipient for 2008. This prize includes an award of about $1.4 million and was given to Krugman for his work associated with New Trade Theory and the New Economic Geography.[56] In the words of the prize committee, "By having integrated economies of scale into explicit general equilibrium models, Paul Krugman has deepened our understanding of the determinants of trade and the location of economic activity."[57]
Awards
[խմբագրել | խմբագրել կոդը]- 1991, American Economic Association, John Bates Clark Medal.[58] Since it was awarded to only one person, once every two years (prior to 2009), The Economist has described the Clark Medal as 'slightly harder to get than a Nobel prize'.[59]
- 1992, Fellow of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences (AAAS).[60]
- 1995, Adam Smith Award of the National Association for Business Economics[61]
- 1998, Doctor honoris causa in Economics awarded by Free University of Berlin Freie Universität Berlin in Germany
- 2000, H.C. Recktenwald Prize in Economics, awarded by University of Erlangen-Nuremberg in Germany.
- 2002, Editor and Publisher, Columnist of the Year.[62]
- 2004, Fundación Príncipe de Asturias (Spain), Prince of Asturias Awards in Social Sciences.[63]
- 2004, Doctor of Humane Letters honoris causa, Haverford College[64]
- 2008, Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics for Krugman's contributions to New Trade Theory.[65] He became the twelfth John Bates Clark Medal winner to be awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize.
- 2011, EPI Distinguished Economist Award.[66]
- 2011 Gerald Loeb Award for Commentary[67]
- 2012, Doctor honoris causa from the Universidade de Lisboa, Universidade Técnica de Lisboa and Universidade Nova de Lisboa[68][69]
- 2013, Doctor of Laws, honoris causa conferred by the University of Toronto, Toronto, Canada [70]
- 2014, recipient of the Literary and Historical Society (University College Dublin)'s James Joyce Award in recognition of his outstanding contribution to the economic sciences.[71]
- 2014, recipient of the Green Templeton College, Oxford's Sanjaya Lall Visiting Professorship of Business and Development, Trinity Term 2014, in recognition of his outstanding international reputation in scholarship and research in the field of Development Economics and Business.[72][73]
- 2016, Doctor of Letters, honoris causa conferred by the University of Oxford, Oxford, UK[74]
A May 2011 Hamilton College analysis of 26 politicians, journalists, and media commentators who made predictions in major newspaper columns or television news shows from September 2007 to December 2008 found that Krugman was the most accurate. Only nine of the prognosticators predicted more accurately than chance, two were significantly less accurate, and the remaining 14 were no better or worse than a coin flip. Krugman was correct in 15 out of 17 predictions, compared to 9 out of 11 for the next most accurate media figure, Maureen Dowd.[75]
Foreign Policy named Krugman one of its 2012 FP Top 100 Global Thinkers "for wielding his acid pen against austerity".[76]
- ↑ «Krugman Curriculum Vitae» (PDF). Արխիվացված (PDF) օրիգինալից March 4, 2016-ին. Վերցված է March 31, 2016-ին.
- ↑ Krugman, Paul (February 28, 2014), «Changes (Personal/Professional)», The New York Times, Արխիվացված օրիգինալից July 26, 2014-ին, Վերցված է July 18, 2014-ին, «I have informed Princeton that I will be retiring at the end of next academic year, that is, in June 2015. In August 2015 I will join the faculty of the Graduate Center, City University of New York, as a professor in the Ph.D. program in economics. I will also become a distinguished scholar at the Graduate Center's Luxembourg Income Study Center.»
- ↑ Քաղվածելու սխալ՝ Սխալ
<ref>
պիտակ՝ «IDEAS
» անվանումով ref-երը տեքստ չեն պարունակում: - ↑ Paul Krugman (December 13, 2009). «Paul Samuelson, RIP». The New York Times. «One of the things Robin Wells and I did when writing our principles of economics textbook was to acquire and study a copy of the original, 1948 edition of Samuelson's textbook.»
- ↑ 5,0 5,1 5,2 Nobel Prize Committee, "The Prize in Economic Sciences 2008" Արխիվացված Օգոստոս 30, 2017 Wayback Machine
- ↑ Arvind Panagariya (October 13, 2008). «Paul Krugman, Nobel». Forbes. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից November 7, 2017-ին. Վերցված է September 7, 2017-ին.
- ↑ Dixit, Avinash; Stiglitz, Joseph (1977). «Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity». American Economic Review. 67 (3): 297–308. JSTOR 1831401.
- ↑ Kikuchi, Toru (2010). «The Dixit-Stiglitz-Krugman Trade Model: A Geometric Note». Discussion Papers from Graduate School of Economics, Kobe University (1006). Արխիվացված օրիգինալից April 25, 2013-ին. Վերցված է August 19, 2012-ին.
- ↑ Rosser, J. Barkley (2011). «2: The New Economic Geography Approach». Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity. Springer. էջ 24. «The workhorse model of this approach since 1991 has been the model of monopolistic competition due to Avinash Dixit and Joseph Stiglitz (1977). It was used by Paul Krugman (1979, 1980) to provide an approach to analyzing increasing returns in international trade.»
- ↑ 10,0 10,1 10,2 10,3 10,4 10,5 Behrens, Kristian; Robert-Nicoud, Frédéric (2009). «Krugman's Papers in Regional Science: The 100 dollar bill on the sidewalk is gone and the 2008 Nobel Prize well-deserved». Papers in Regional Science. 88 (2): 467–89. doi:10.1111/j.1435-5957.2009.00241.x.
- ↑ Krugman, P. (1981). «Trade, accumulation, and uneven development». Journal of Development Economics. 8 (2): 149–61. doi:10.1016/0304-3878(81)90026-2. hdl:10419/160238.
- ↑ Paul Krugman. https://www.ubs.com/microsites/nobel-perspectives/en/paul-krugman.html(չաշխատող հղում) in UBS Nobel Perspectives interview, 2008.
- ↑ "Bold strokes: a strong economic stylist wins the Nobel" Արխիվացված Հոկտեմբեր 21, 2008 Wayback Machine, The Economist, October 16, 2008.
- ↑ Քաղվածելու սխալ՝ Սխալ
<ref>
պիտակ՝ «smokymountain
» անվանումով ref-երը տեքստ չեն պարունակում: - ↑ (He writes on p. xxvi of his book The Great Unraveling that "I still have the angry letter Ralph Nader sent me when I criticized his attacks on globalization.")
- ↑ Strategic trade policy and the new international economics, Paul R. Krugman (ed), The MIT Press, p. 18, 978-0-262-61045-2
- ↑ "Honoring Paul Krugman" Արխիվացված Դեկտեմբեր 26, 2017 Wayback Machine Economix blog of The New York Times, Edward Glaeser, October 13, 2008.
- ↑ Krugman (1999) "Was it all in Ohlin?" Արխիվացված Մայիս 23, 2009 Wayback Machine
- ↑ Krugman PR (2008), "Interview with the 2008 laureate in economics Paul Krugman" Արխիվացված Հուլիս 26, 2010 Wayback Machine, December 6, 2008. Stockholm, Sweden.
- ↑ Քաղվածելու սխալ՝ Սխալ
<ref>
պիտակ՝ «forbes131008
» անվանումով ref-երը տեքստ չեն պարունակում: - ↑ «Archived copy» (PDF). Արխիվացված (PDF) օրիգինալից December 1, 2017-ին. Վերցված է November 22, 2017-ին.
{{cite web}}
: CS1 սպաս․ արխիվը պատճենվել է որպես վերնագիր (link) - ↑ «Currency Crises». Web.mit.edu. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից March 28, 2010-ին. Վերցված է 2011-10-04-ին.
- ↑ Sarno, Lucio; Mark P. Taylor (2002). The Economics of Exchange Rates. Cambridge University Press. էջեր 245–64. ISBN 978-0-521-48584-5.
- ↑ Craig Burnside, Martin Eichenbaum, and Sergio Rebelo (2008), "Currency crisis models" Արխիվացված Հոկտեմբեր 28, 2008 Wayback Machine, New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd ed.
- ↑ "The International Finance Multiplier", P. Krugman, October 2008
- ↑ "Global Economic Integration and Decoupling" Արխիվացված Հունիս 22, 2009 Wayback Machine, Donald L. Kohn, speech at the International Research Forum on Monetary policy, Frankfurt, Germany, 06-26-2008; from website for the Board of Governors for the Federal Reserve System. Retrieved 08-20-2009, June 26, 2008
- ↑ Nayan Chanda, YaleGlobal Online, orig. from Businessworld February 8, 2008 "Decoupling Demystified" Արխիվացված Մայիս 15, 2011 Wayback Machine
- ↑ "The myth of decoupling," Sebastien Walti, February 2009
- ↑ "The International Finance Multiplier" Արխիվացված Դեկտեմբեր 22, 2018 Wayback Machine, The Conscience of a Liberal (blog), 10-05-2008. Retrieved 09-20-2009
- ↑ Andrew Leonard, "Krugman: 'We are all Brazilians now'", "How the World Works" Արխիվացված Մայիս 3, 2009 Wayback Machine, 10-07-2008
- ↑ "Krugman: The International Finance Multiplier", Mark Thoma, Economist's View, 10-06-2008, [1] Արխիվացված Հունվար 2, 2010 Wayback Machine
- ↑ O'Brien, R; Keith, A (2009). «The geography of finance: after the storm». Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society. 2 (2): 245–65. doi:10.1093/cjres/rsp015.
- ↑ Japanese fixed income markets: money, bond and interest rate derivatives, Jonathan Batten, Thomas A. Fetherston, Peter G. Szilagyi (eds.) Elsevier Science, November 30, 2006, 978-0-444-52020-3 p. 137 Արխիվացված Սեպտեմբեր 15, 2015 Wayback Machine
- ↑ Ben Bernanke, "Japanese Monetary Policy: a case of self-induced paralysis?", in Japan's financial crisis and its parallels to U.S. experience, Ryōichi Mikitani, Adam Posen (ed), Institute for International Economics, October 2000 978-0-88132-289-7 p. 157 Արխիվացված Մայիս 30, 2015 Wayback Machine
- ↑ "Some Observations on the Return of the Liquidity Trap" Արխիվացված Սեպտեմբեր 6, 2009 Wayback Machine, Scott Sumner, Cato Journal, Vol. 21, No. 3 (Winter 2002).
- ↑ Reconstructing Macroeconomics: Structuralist Proposals and Critiques of the Mainstream, Lance Taylor, Harvard University Press, p. 159: "Kregel (2000) points out that there are at least three theories of the liquidity trap in the literature – Keynes own analyses ... Hicks' [in] 1936 and 1937 ... and a view that can be attributed to Fisher in the 1930s and Paul Krugman in latter days"
- ↑ Paul Krugman. «Paul Krugman's Japan page». Web.mit.edu. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից October 20, 2008-ին. Վերցված է 2011-10-04-ին.
- ↑ Krugman, Paul R.; Dominquez, Kathryn M.; Rogoff, Kenneth (1998). «It's Baaack: Japan's Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap» (PDF). Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 1998 (2): 137–205. doi:10.2307/2534694. JSTOR 2534694.
- ↑ 39,0 39,1 Krugman, Paul (2000), "Thinking About the Liquidity Trap" Արխիվացված Օգոստոս 25, 2009 Wayback Machine, Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, v.14, no.4, Dec 2000, pp. 221–37.
- ↑ "Reply to Nelson and Schwartz", Paul Krugman, Journal of Monetary Economics, v. 55, no. 4, pp. 857–60 05-23-2008
- ↑ Krugman, Paul (1999). "The Return of Depression Economics", pp. 70–77. W. W. Norton, New York 0-393-04839-X
- ↑ "Japan's Trap", May 2008. [2] Արխիվացված Օգոստոս 19, 2009 Wayback Machine Retrieved 08-22-2009
- ↑ "Further Notes on Japan's Liquidity Trap" Արխիվացված Հոկտեմբեր 1, 2009 Wayback Machine, Paul Krugman
- ↑ Restoring Japan's economic growth, Adam Posen, Petersen Institute, September 1, 1998, 978-0-88132-262-0 , p. 123 Արխիվացված Սեպտեմբեր 15, 2015 Wayback Machine,
- ↑ "What is wrong with Japan?", Nihon Keizai Shinbun, 1997 [3] Արխիվացված Սեպտեմբեր 11, 2009 Wayback Machine
- ↑ Krugman, Paul (June 15, 2009). «Stay the Course». The New York Times. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից May 11, 2011-ին. Վերցված է August 15, 2009-ին.
- ↑ "Some Reasons Why a New Crisis Needs a New Paradigm of Economic Thought" Արխիվացված Օգոստոս 6, 2009 Wayback Machine, Keiichiro Kobayashi, RIETI Report No.108, Research Institute of Economy, Trade & Industry (Japan), 07-31-2009
- ↑ Robert Skidelsky (2009). Keynes: The Return of the Master. Allen Lane. էջեր 47–50, 58. ISBN 978-1-84614-258-1.
- ↑ Noah Smith (March 21, 2012). «Die the Krugman insurgency fail?». Brad DeLong. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից August 25, 2013-ին. Վերցված է 2012-05-29-ին.
- ↑ Henry Farrell and John Quiggin (March 2012). «Consensus, Dissensus and Economic Ideas: The Rise and Fall of Keynesianism During the Economic Crisis» (PDF). The Center for the Study of Development Strategies. Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից (PDF) August 25, 2013-ին. Վերցված է 2012-05-29-ին.
- ↑ Cochrane, John. "How Did Paul Krugman Get It So Wrong?" Արխիվացված Մարտ 4, 2016 Wayback Machine, Institute of Economic Affairs, 2011.
- ↑ Paul Krugman and Richard Layard (June 27, 2012). «A Manifesto for Economic Sense». Արխիվացված օրիգինալից July 12, 2012-ին. Վերցված է 2012-07-11-ին.
- ↑ David Blanchflower (July 2, 2012). «David Blanchflower: Yet more nails in Osborne's economic coffin». The Independent. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից June 14, 2015-ին. Վերցված է 2012-07-11-ին.
- ↑ Katrina vanden Heuvel (July 9, 2012). «Krugman's Manifesto for Economic Common Sense». The Nation. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից July 11, 2012-ին. Վերցված է 2012-07-11-ին.
- ↑ Stephen King (chief economist HSBC) (July 9, 2012). «Krugman and Layard suffer from optimism bias». Financial Times. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից July 11, 2012-ին. Վերցված է 2012-07-11-ին.
- ↑ Catherine Rampell (October 13, 2008). «Paul Krugman Wins Economics Nobel». Economix.blogs.nytimes.com. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից October 14, 2008-ին. Վերցված է October 13, 2008-ին.
- ↑ Prize Committee of the Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, October 13, 2008, Scientific background on the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel 2008, "Trade and Geography – Economies of Scale, Differentiated Products and Transport Costs" Արխիվացված Օգոստոս 30, 2017 Wayback Machine
- ↑ Avinash Dixit, The Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 7, No. 2 (Spring, 1993), pp. 173–88, In Honor of Paul Krugman: Winner of the John Bates Clark Medal Արխիվացված Հունիս 4, 2016 Wayback Machine, Retrieved March 28, 2007.
- ↑ Քաղվածելու սխալ՝ Սխալ
<ref>
պիտակ՝ «onehanded
» անվանումով ref-երը տեքստ չեն պարունակում: - ↑ Քաղվածելու սխալ՝ Սխալ
<ref>
պիտակ՝ «PWB
» անվանումով ref-երը տեքստ չեն պարունակում: - ↑ «Adam Smith Award». Nabe.com. Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից September 27, 2011-ին. Վերցված է 2011-10-04-ին.
- ↑ Mother Jones: Paul Krugman Արխիվացված Դեկտեմբեր 6, 2008 Wayback Machine., August 7, 2005. Retrieved March 28, 2007.
- ↑ Paul Krugman Արխիվացված Սեպտեմբեր 29, 2007 Wayback Machine, 2004. Retrieved March 28, 2007.
- ↑ «Citation presented by Linda Bell, Associate Professor of Economics». Haverford.edu. May 28, 2004. Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից January 18, 2012-ին. Վերցված է 2011-10-04-ին.
- ↑ «Nobel Prize in Economics». Swedish Academy. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից October 14, 2008-ին. Վերցված է October 13, 2008-ին.
- ↑ «EPI at 25: Honoring Paul Krugman». Economic Policy Institute. 2011-11-01. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից December 6, 2017-ին. Վերցված է 2017-12-05-ին.
- ↑ «Loeb Award Winners». UCLA Anderson School of Management. June 28, 2011. Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից March 21, 2019-ին. Վերցված է February 2, 2019-ին.
- ↑ «Honoris Causa a Paul Krugman» (պորտուգալերեն). Universidade Nova de Lisboa. Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից August 18, 2012-ին. Վերցված է 2012-03-19-ին.
- ↑ «Paul Krugman: Doctor honoris causa by three Portuguese universities». Portuguese American Journal. February 28, 2012. Վերցված է March 19, 2012-ին.
- ↑ «Honorary graduate Paul Krugman». University of Toronto. June 14, 2013. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից June 14, 2013-ին. Վերցված է 2013-06-16-ին.
- ↑ «Economist Professor Paul Krugman receives James Joyce Award from UCD Literary & Historical Society». University College Dublin. January 14, 2014. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից January 16, 2014-ին. Վերցված է 2014-01-15-ին.
- ↑ «Welcome Professor Krugman as the Sanjaya Lall Visiting Professor of Business and Development». Green Templeton College, Oxford. May 7, 2014. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից February 18, 2014-ին. Վերցված է 2014-05-07-ին.
- ↑ College, Green Templeton. «Home». Green Templeton College. Արխիվացված օրիգինալից January 9, 2019-ին. Վերցված է January 7, 2019-ին.
- ↑ «Oxford announces honorary degrees for 2016 | University of Oxford». Արխիվացված օրիգինալից July 13, 2016-ին. Վերցված է April 27, 2016-ին.
- ↑ Donaldson et al. (May, 2011) "Are Talking Heads Blowing Hot Air? An Analysis of the Accuracy of Forecasts in the Political Media" Արխիվացված Հոկտեմբեր 31, 2012 Wayback Machine Hamilton Public Policy Project
- ↑ «The FP Top 100 Global Thinkers». Foreign Policy. November 26, 2012. Արխիվացված է օրիգինալից November 30, 2012-ին. Վերցված է November 28, 2012-ին.